[syndicated profile] galwednesday_tumblr_feed

specialagentartemis:

“Be curious about what you’re writing about” is not stock Common Writing Advice but it really, really should be. There are a lot of written works that fail due to the authors just being obviously incurious about what they are writing about.

[syndicated profile] ximen_tumblr_feed

WHAT? ARE YOU MY PARALYSIS DEMON???

Here you go...

Black-headed Parrot (Pionites melanocephalus), EAT TASTY FRUIT!!!, family Psittacidae, order Psittaciformes, Colombia

photograph by ruedacamara

Red-ruffed Fruitcrow (Pyroderus scutatus), EAT A TASTY FRUIT!!!, family Cotingidae, order Passeriformes, Colombia

photograph by Juan Jacobo Castillo

Resplendent Quetzal (Pharomachrus mocinno), male, EAT A TASTY FRUIT!!!, family Trogonidae, Cerro de la Muerte, Costa Rica

photograph by javier_zurita_photography

Curl-crested Araçari (Pteroglossus beauharnaisii) EAT A TASTY FRUIT!!!, family Ramphastidae, order Picidae, from West-central South America

photograph by Jim Frazee

Rose-crowned Fruit-Dove (Ptilinopus regina) EAT A TASTY FRUIT!!!, male, family Columbidae, order Columbiformes, QLD, Australia

photograph by C. Charles

[syndicated profile] galwednesday_tumblr_feed

eggsac:

daemoninwhiteround2:

writing omegaverse CPR because apparently that’s how my brain expresses itself these days

I didn’t realize this referred to a ship and was super confused at why omegaverse cardiopulmonary resuscitation would different from non-omegaverse, like oh no what does the knot do now

[syndicated profile] ximen_tumblr_feed

xiangqiankua:

您們好 請不要把家裡「垃圾」或者“沒吃完”「食物」丟在垃圾桶,很容易長出蟲蟲,會很難打掃。謝謝您

I will admit it’s easier to write 虫 (simplified), however with 蟲蟲 one really gets a sense of exactly how many insects are going to 長出來 if you leave uneaten food in the laundromat 垃圾桶.

[syndicated profile] ximen_tumblr_feed

Oh me too! This always makes the list of favorite birds for me!

Kakapo aka Owl Parrot (Strigops habroptila), family Strigopidae, order Psittaciformes, New Zealand

CRITICALLY ENDANGERED.

Photographs by the New Zealand department of conservation

photograph: Department of Conservation- Peter Drury

photograph: Department of Conservation - Kakapo Sirocco

[syndicated profile] hope_for_the_planet_feed

life-on-our-planet:

A small herd of dun colored wild horses swishing their tails, slowly milling about and grazing on the tall green grasses around them. ALT
Three wild horses head down a gentle hillside, only one briefly glancing at the camera.ALT
An adult and foal stand close to each other and swish their tails and manes. ALT
Three wild horses walking together through lower grass, with the sun low behind them and their shadows long in front of them. ALT
Three adult horses and a foal stand together grazing. ALT
Three of the horses stop and glance at the camera, seeming interested but unafraid. Please don't worry, this footage was taken from a distance by a wildlife photographer who's experienced filming in the Chernobyl area! These horses will stay wild and safe. ALT

Although it was once extinct in the wild the takhi has been successfully reintroduced to its native territory in Central China and Eastern Europe.
©ChornobylWild

This species only exists because many, many humans cared enough to invest tremendous effort in stopping it from going extinct. And now they’ve been de-listed from extinct in the wild to just endangered.

I believe these gifs are specifically from the herd that was released into the Chernobyl Exclusion Zone when the species was still extinct in the wild. That herd is estimated to be about 100 strong now.

Something, something, life finds a way.

[syndicated profile] galwednesday_tumblr_feed

valencians:

“y'all’s” is the best regional solution to the english second person plural possessive problem but “your guyses” is my favorite because it sucks

[syndicated profile] acoup_feed

Posted by Bret Devereaux

This is the first post in a series discussing the basic contours of life – birth, marriage, labor, subsistence, death – of pre-modern peasants and their families. Prior to the industrial revolution, peasant farmers of varying types made up the overwhelming majority of people in settled societies (the sort with cities and writing). And when I say overwhelming, I mean overwhelming: we generally estimate these societies to have consisted of upwards of 80% peasant farmers, often as high as 90 or even 95%. Yet when we talk about these periods, we are often focused on aristocrats, priests, knights, warriors, kings and literate bureaucrats, the sort of folks who write to us or on smiths, masons and artists, the sort of folk whose work sometimes survives for us to see. But this series is going to be about what life was like for the great majority of people who lived in small farming households.

We’re actually doing two things in this series. First, of course, we’ll be discussing what we know about the patterns of life for peasant households. But we’re also laying out a method. The tricky thing with discussing peasants, after all, is that they generally do note write to us (not being literate) and the writers we do have from the past are generally uninterested in them. This is a mix of snobbery – aristocrats rarely actually care very much how the ‘other half’ (again, the other 95%) live – but also a product of familiarity: it was simply unnecessary to describe what life for the peasantry was like because everyone could see it and most people were living it. But that can actually make investigating the lives of these farming folks quite hard, because their lives are almost never described to us as such. Functionally no one in antiquity or the middle ages is writing a biography of a small peasant farmer who remained a peasant farmer their whole life.1 But the result is that I generally cannot tell you the story of a specific ancient or medieval small peasant farmer.

What we can do, however is uncover the lives of these peasant households through modeling. Because we mostly do have enough scattered evidence to chart the basic contours, as very simply mathematical models, of what it was like to live in these households: when one married, the work one did, the household size, and so on. So while I cannot pick a poor small farmer from antiquity and tell you their story, I can, in a sense, tell you the story of every small farmer in the aggregate, modeling our best guess at what a typical small farming household would look like.

So that’s what we’re going to do here. This week we’re going to introduce our basic building blocks, households and villages, and talk about their shape and particularly their size. Then next week (hopefully), we’ll get into marriage, birth and mortality patterns to talk about why they are the size they are. Then, ideally, the week after that, we’ll talk about labor and survival for these households: how they produce enough to survive, generation to generation and what ‘survival’ means. And throughout, we’ll get a sense of both what a ‘typical’ peasant household might look and work like, and also the tools historians use to answer those questions.

But first, a necessary caveat: I am a specialist on the Roman economy and so my ‘default’ is to use estimates and data from the Roman Republic and Roman Empire (mostly the latter). I have some grounding in modeling other ancient and medieval economies in the broader Mediterranean, where the staple crops are wheat and barley (which matters). So the models we’re going to set up are going to be most applicable in that space: towards the end of antiquity in the Mediterranean. They’ll also be pretty applicable to the European/Mediterranean Middle Ages and some parts – particularly mortality patterns – are going to apply universally to all pre-modern agrarian societies. I’ll try to be clear as we move what elements of the model are which are more broadly universal and which are very context sensitive (meaning they differ place-to-place or period-to-period) and to the degree I can say, how they vary. But our ‘anchor point’ is going to be the Romans, operating in the (broadly defined) iron age, at the tail end of antiquity.

But first, if you like what you are reading, please share it and if you really like it, you can support this project on Patreon! While I do teach as the academic equivalent of a tenant farmer, tilling the Big Man’s classes, this project is my little plot of freeheld land which enables me to keep working as a writers and scholar. And if you want updates whenever a new post appears, you can click below for email updates or follow me on Twitter and Bluesky and (less frequently) Mastodon (@bretdevereaux@historians.social) for updates when posts go live and my general musings; I have largely shifted over to Bluesky (I maintain some de minimis presence on Twitter), given that it has become a much better place for historical discussion than Twitter.

From the British Museum (1850,0713.103), a print of a village scene – a festive dance – in Holland in 1748. I want to include as many of these sorts of images as I can because our instinct is to think about ‘peasants’ and ‘villages’ as dirty and muddy and brown but these are people who like to be clean and look nice and have festivals where they play music and dance.

(Bibliography Note: The standard first-stop reading for a general overview of the structures of pre-modern society is P. Crone, Pre-Industrial Societies: Anatomy of the Pre-Modern World (1989), although it is somewhat older and does not engage in the sort of statistical modeling here. Agricultural modeling here follows P. Erdkamp, The Grain Market in the Roman Empire: A Social, Political and Economic Study (2005), N. Rosenstein, Rome at War: Farms, Families, and Death in the Middle Republic (2004). Note also M. Bloch, La Société Féodale (1940; available trans. Manyon, 1962) and E.L.R. Ladurie, Les Paysans de Languedoc (1966; available trans. J. Day, 1976) and T.W. Gallant, Risk and Survival in Ancient Greece: Reconstructing the Rural Domestic Economy (1991). Demographic modeling follows B. Frier, “Demography,” CAH2 XI (2000); note also W. Scheidel, Death on the Nile (2001), R. Bagnall and B. Frier, The Demography of Roman Egypt (1994) for Egyptian demographic data as well as R.P. Saller, Patriarchy, property and death in the Roman Family (1994) for the same in Italy. Additional bibliography on farming, textiles and demography are available in the previous blog posts that focused on them.)

Building Blocks

We want to begin by thinking about the basic constituent units of pre-modern agrarian societies. But before we launch in, I want to note that we are, somewhat unavoidably starting in the middle here. Household, farm and village sizes are, of course, products of patterns of marriage, births, deaths and the economic underpinnings of farming life, which we’re going to discuss, but not yet. But those patterns also depend on the sizes of households and farms and so on; the thing wraps around on itself and we have to start somewhere. We’re starting here, with the size of households and their landholdings for two reasons: first, it is conceptually simpler to do so than to start with the demography that produces these households, because that demography is easier to explain through ‘model’ families of a given size.

But second, this is where our evidence generally starts as well. After all, our sources do not generally record demographic or economic statistics.2 Instead, what we have to work with are usually surviving records – often fragmentary – which often give us a single snapshot of a community in a moment of time. Another key source of evidence is funerary evidence – records of death, tombstones, other dedications – which also offer us not a complete history of a family but a snapshot of it in a single (quite sad) moment in time. We have to work backwards, as we’ll see in the next several posts, from those ‘snapshots’ to a complete model of a society ‘in motion.’ So even though the snapshot is a product of the processes we’re going to discuss, we’re going to start with the snapshot and the snapshot starts with households.

We are used to thinking about this question in terms of individuals, but this is a modern framework, both culturally and economically. As a cultural notion, modern societies tend to be quite a bit more individualistic than pre-modern societies, for reasons that, I suspect, are going to become clear as we go. But for economic reasons, while an individual in a modern society can hold a job, pay their bills and generally live ‘on their own,’ effectively no peasant farmer can run their farm alone.

Instead, the initial basic unit of society in the pre-modern, pre-industrial world was the household, which almost always functioned as both a social unit (these folks lived together) and an economic unit, which pooled resources and labor collectively. We tend to associate households with nuclear families (a parent-pair and their children) and indeed the most common sort of pre-modern households generally have a nuclear family at their core, but that is hardly the only form and even nuclear-family-based households often have ‘add-ons’ – (from the children’s sense) grandparents, uncles, aunts, cousins and also in many of these societies various forms of non-free dependent laborers, which is to say slaves.

We’ll get back to the structure of households in just a moment, but before we do, we need to establish the next key unit: a group of households makes a village. Modern folks, especially Americans, often think of ‘farms’ in the form of a homestead: a single isolated farming household (often on quite a bit of land) generally well away from other households or settlements. But pre-modern communities are almost never organized this way. Instead, a number of households nucleates together to form a village, a small farming settlement; villages tend to be anywhere from ten to a few dozen households in size. In some societies, land is understood to be really held by the village, but certainly in the broader Mediterranean it was more common for land associated with the village to be mostly owned by the household (with some ‘common’ areas held by the village). However even where land is privately held, the village often is understood to have some collective claims on the land, sometimes formally defined, sometimes informally defined. After all, the village exists precisely because the single farming household isn’t really a sustainable social or economic unit on its own. As we’ve discussed before, pre-modern farmers rely on close relationships between households to survive, which – combined with these being relatively less individualistic societies – tends to mean that the members of a village broadly understand themselves to have a right to be in each other’s business to a meaningful degree.

From the British Museum (Sheepshanks.4784), an etching of a village scene, 1640.

We’ll come back to the village in a moment when we talk about land holdings, but let’s first return to our households.

The Structure of a Household

Now, I keep saying household rather than ‘family,’ because pre-modern households tend to be rather more complex than our idealized image of a modern ‘nuclear’ (two parents and their children) family, although to be fair, modern households are also often more complex than that idealized image. The instinct we tend to have about past households is that of a complete ‘stem’ household – multiple generations, in their entirety, living together – often leading to the assumption of very large households in the pre-modern period. In practice, some of the assumptions there are right, but many of the conclusions are wrong and it is best to rebuild our assumptions about these households from scratch.

When we say ‘household,’ we want to be clear that we mean an economic unit that almost always includes a core family, but may include individuals beyond that family: enslaved laborers, longer-term hired workers, lodgers, distant kin and so on. It is important, as an aside, to be really careful about words that feel like ‘family’ in ancient languages: Latin familia means ‘household,’ not family and includes those enslaved dependents, as does Greek oikos (‘house’). The household is the unit of people generally living together which in these societies generally functions as a single economic unit (that is, household members do not – generally legally do not – have an independent economic existence from each other).

Needless to say the household is not understood as a collection of equals, but exists in a hierarchy. The Romans actually define this hierarchy legally: the pater familias – the ‘father of the family’ (defined as a male with no living male, male-line ancestors)3 exerted full legal authority over all members of the household, including adults. The women and children of the household were under the direction of the mater familias (herself under the legal control of the pater familias, recall), generally the wife of the pater familias, who exerted non-legal, customary but very real authority over them. The mater familias also had charge over enslaved household staff. Enslaved workers were in turn subordinate to all of the free members of the household (which, for societies where outside laborers might be free wage-laborers, this is generally where they fit too: the bottom rung). Other societies might define the hierarchy in the household more or less clearly (for societies with written laws, it is generally legally defined and enforceable in court) but the hierarchy and its basic pattern tend to be quite similar across cultures.

https://upload.wikimedia.org/wikipedia/commons/0/02/Les_Tr%C3%A8s_Riches_Heures_du_duc_de_Berry_f%C3%A9vrier.jpg
Via Wikipedia, an illuminated page (f.2v) from the Très Riches Heures du Duc de Berry, a book of hours (1412-1416). We see a peasant farmhouse with two men and a woman warming themselves by a fire, while several more work outside. A small village is visible in the distance not too far away. These manuscript illustrations are also valuable reminders that peasant dress and life was not endlessly drab: note the bright colors of much of the clothing. People liked to look nice!

That said actual households can often be complex in their structure when we see them in the evidence and the reason for this is that the household represents the uneasy collision of two systems which are, in the moral vision of these societies, supposed to align, but which often don’t.4 Generally speaking, the ideal these societies have is for the claim to the farmland that makes up the economic basis of the household and the biological family that makes up its core to be co-extensive (a Venn-diagram that makes a single circle, in a sense). What is supposed to happen is that a father is supposed to have enough land to divide between his (male) heirs – the Romans call this inherited property patrimonium – who in turn pass this on to the next generation and so on. But of course in practice the biological family might not line up well with the property: you might have a farm too small to split, with more than one heir, resulting in the pater familias‘ sibling being in the household. Or you might have a household without enough labor to farm all of the land, so more distant relatives might move in.

These complex households are created by a relatively simple but important interaction: in a society where there is very limited wage labor and so life without land is very hard, families are extremely reluctant to kick any familiar member or relation off of the farm. As a result there is a strong desire to keep family members inside the household, leading to complex structures. This is going, as we’ll see, to result in families that are often awkwardly large as units of labor for the farms they have (that is, they’re long on people and short on land), but they don’t ‘right-size’ to the farmland because they’re unwilling to exposed beloved relatives to poverty and starvation unless they absolutely have to.

The normal formation pattern for these sorts of complex households is that children who marry don’t immediately move out (move to where? there’s only the one farm and very few opportunities outside of it), creating a complex family of elderly parents, their adult children (and spouses) and their children’s children. As those parents pass away, we might end with the head of household’s brothers remaining (because where else would they go) sometimes termed a frérèche. As we’ll see when we get to mortality, the frequency of death in these societies may also layer these complex households with multiple marriages even in non-divorce cultures and you might also have a situation where, say, the children of the head of household’s deceased brother are present. And then on top of this as noted, you might have enslaved laborers or various kinds of lodgers or in-dwellers: distant kin, hired hands, and so on.

Now the instinct is to then assume that these households must generally be enormous, because they are so complex and main thus contain multiple linked nuclear families (“and didn’t everyone have a ton of kids back then?” – we’ll get back to this). In practice these households are larger than typical modern households, but by a lot less than you think and also the statistics here can be deceptive in terms of what they actually mean.

From the British Museum (1850,0713.101), a Flemish peasant farmhouse. When we talk about households, we can think as much about the place as the people. Note also how these village farmhouses are both living spaces and working spaces (and note you can see the core of this village just behind, with the top of the church steeple poking above the trees).

We can jump to the ‘topline’ figures and then spend a bunch of time explaining them. Households in pre-modern societies vary wildly in size, but the average size tends to live in a reasonably small range, varying roughly around four to five-and-change persons5 (compared to the average household size in the United States for a family is 3.14; globally the average is 4.9).6 That said, while the average is reasonably consistent between societies, within a society we can find households in a very wide range of sizes, from single-person households (typically the result of the deaths of other household members, rather than fission) to very large, complex households with 10 or more members.

However that topline figure can be deceptive in a few ways.

The first is that it is a snapshot which is going to catch households in a range of different stages of their existence, which plays with our perceptions in odd ways. The big problem is that when I say “the average household has five members” what folks tend to hear is “the average household peaked in size at five members” but that is, of course, not what we have said. We have said that in our snapshot of a single moment in time the average household has four or five members – across many households at various states of growth and contraction!

To get a sense of what I mean, we’re going to dive a bit into the figures for Roman Egypt offered by Bagnall and Frier, op. cit., which reflect data on around 300 households (of which they have complete census returns for about half). Fully 16.2% of the households in their set were solitary – a single family member living without kin.7 Obviously those households exert significant downward pressure on the average. Our very modern instinct is to interpret these households as bachelors and spinsters, a household that began as and remained solitary – we mentally project out their current state outside of the snapshot. But that is very unlikely to have been the story of these households, if for no other reason than – and we’ll get to this later in the series – nuptiality (the rate at which individuals get married)8 was extremely high; in Roman Egypt the marriage rate was likely in excess of 95%.9 Instead, these solitary households typically represent individuals who are the last survivor of what was once a larger household. So for instance, a man who married (this works the same if we flip the genders of the survivor, I should note), had three daughters and no sons might – his wife having passed and his daughters married – show up as a solitary ‘family’ of one – but obvious his experience of life was not as a solitary householder, but as the member of a family of (at least) five. For a lot of folks, their intuition is this man’s ‘household number’ is ‘five’ not ‘one,’ but of course it is one in the snapshot.

In short, what we’re running into is the distinction between average household size and average completed household size, which is the term I’ve seen used to mean, in essence, peak household size. Now average completed family size, just mathematically under the mortality conditions we see in antiquity, is going to be right around five, too. It can’t actually be much different: much lower and population shrinks, but it can’t push much higher under the conditions of such high mortality.10 But as we’ve noted, a lot of these households include non-kin residents (slaves, hired hands, etc.) or near-kin outside of the core family. So an average completed household size would necessarily be larger, but more difficult to calculate and I haven’t seen a solid estimate for it. Going by what I have seen, I’d take a stab around 6 to 8 for the average completed household size: multiple family households tend to be as common or more common than conjugal (husband+wife+children only) households in the data11 and they typically mean a mean household size roughly double that of conjugal families.12

At the other end, breaking our intuitive sense of what “an average household size of five” means is the other side of mortality: extremely high child mortality. When I say “an average household size of five,” we moderns think in terms of a family tree. But this is a snapshot! As we’ll see, a core family of, say, four (with perhaps one non-family household member) might be a single married pair and two (living) children, but their family tree likely includes roughly two deceased children who never lived to adulthood (along with, moving up a level, two deceased siblings), who, being deceased, are not counted in the snapshot. Equally, children who will be born are also not counted in the snapshot. So we’re not measuring households at their maximum size (how we tend to think about it, in my experience) but their size at the moment of measurement in our sources.

The second way that the ‘average’ household size is a bit deceptive is that it’s an average per household not per person. But precisely because households larger than average are larger than average more people will tend to live in them. So for instance, Bagnall and Frier (op. cit., 67-9) note the average household size in their census data from Roman Egypt is roughly 5, but this is in a data-set where 40% of the people live in multiple-family-households (that is a household with at least two conjugal couples) – 50% in the villages! as these complex families seem more common in the countryside than in town – with a mean size of almost 10 persons, so a smaller number of larger households contain a disproportionate amount of the people. The average household size is five, but at any given moment in time, most of the people are living in households somewhat larger than this.

Now I want to be clear how those large households form, because they are not generally jumbo-sized families, but rather multiple families in a single household. As various scholars have noted,13 a single family household of only co-resident kin under conditions of pre-modern mortality – again, we’ll discuss this later – simply isn’t going to ever have an average size much above 5. (Grand)parents don’t live long enough, too many children die young and so on, forcing the average back down. So when we’re talking about larger households – which do exist! – we’re talking either about households with non-near-kin residents (slaves, workers, etc.) or we’re talking about two families (that is, two married pairs with their children) bolted together in a single household. Which is exactly what we see in Bagnall and Frier, op. cit.‘s data: the big households are almost invariably multiple-family households.

If we want to ask not “what is the average household size” but rather “what size household is the average person living in” (a less useful statistic for demographers, but more useful to get a sense of the society) we get a higher number. Going back to Bagnall and Frier’s dataset, by my math, if we weight households by the number of household members (note: household, not family, so we’re counting slaves, etc.) we end up with the average person living in a household of roughly 6.5 people, which may provide a better sense of what a ‘typical’ peasant household looks like. This is why, by the by, when asked “how large were their households” despite the statistical household average being ‘five,’ I often answer with a range of around five to seven, which tends to capture what people are actually trying to grasp, which is how large a household is the average person in or how large is the average completed household.

Via Wikipedia, another illuminated page (f.9v) from the Très Riches Heures du Duc de Berry, a book of hours (1412-1416), showing a large idealized castle and peasants in the fields arund it. Once again, note that even working in the fields, the peasants are dressed relatively smartly, with well-fitted and colorful clothing. The portrayal is idealizing, of course, but not inaccurate to medieval peasant clothing!

As we’re going to see when we get into it, even that figure conceals a lot of variability, particularly in mortality, but for now, “around five to seven” will have to do.

If that’s the size of the household, how large is their peasant farm?

Landholdings

Small.

We’ve actually done this exercise before, but we can lay out pretty quickly a set of examples. Note that we’re trying here to capture a specific kind of farm: the peasant farm. So we’re going to exclude examples of land allotments designed as estates (where the owner isn’t expected to be doing any farming).

Although farms as small as 1 iugera (0.623 acres) are reported in our sources, our evidence suggests the typical size for Roman smallholding farms was around 5-10 iugera (3.12-6.23 acres).14 The derivation of heredium, which means both ‘a hereditary farm’ and a unit of two iugera, suggests it was imagined at some point as something like the ‘minimum viable farm’ at c. 1.25 acres. The archetypal figure for pre-Han Northern China (also a wheat farming region at this point) was 100 mu (4.764 acres).15 Land allotments for native Egyptian infantrymen (machimoi) in Ptolemaic Egypt, intended to be worked by those soldiers, were in units of 5, 7 or 10 arouras (roughly 3.4, 4.8 or 6.8 acres).16 Somewhat larger, Gallant notes of Classical Greek colonial foundations that four to six hectares (9.8-14.83 acres) were considered typical in colonial foundations.17

Finally, in a survey of land holdings in Saint-Thibery (Languedoc, France) in 1460 AD, the land was astonishingly concentrated. Measured in setérée (1/5th to 1/4th of a hectare (0.49-0.62 acres), an inexact unit of measurement), out of 189 households and 4,500 setérée of land, 100 households (out of 189) on farms of less than 20 setérée (12 acres or so; the setérée appears to be an inexact unit of measurement); 75 of those were on less than 10 setérée (about 6 acres), with neither figure counting the 33 households on 1 setérée (~0.6 acre) or less.18 Another 24 households were between 20 and 40 setérées (12-24 acres). So the great bulk of households were on very small lots indeed and almost certainly relied substantially on working the often much larger holdings of a handful of wealthier households.19

Maps from W. Lee, “Pylos Regional Archaeological Project, Part IV: Change and the Human Landscape in a Modern Greek Village in Messenia” Hesperia 70.1 (2001): 49-98. The paths are connecting fields (especially orchards in this region) along with linking up to other local villages. The intensity of the roads in the NE of the map is because this is where most of Maryeli’s village territory is (check out the cited article for a map of the boundaries between Maryeli and neighboring villages). Note how the complexity of the paths signals the non-regular field divisions.

This is, as we’ve noted before, the other side of the “no one is going to leave their beloved family members to starve unless they have to:” if a peasant household has multiple heirs and it could divide the landholdings down to provide more of them the ability to form households and survive, it does. But the result is that over time, peasant holdings tend to fractionalize down to the smallest possible farm capable of supporting a household. Land quality, household size and what qualified as a ‘respectable’ amount of production (in terms of surviving and also aquiring non-agricultural goods) varied, but that pressure to fractionalize leads household sizes to broadly cluster in that 3-8 acre range (we’ll talk about what the households on even smaller plots are doing later in the series too). Of course that is a fairly big range in the sense that an 8 acre farm is twice the size of a 4 acre farm, so the range here is relatively wide. But one fact worth noting here is that this is a lot less land than the households we discussed above can generally work.

This land was almost never in a single large parcel the way we imagine a modern homestead. Instead, you will recall, these farming households, each with their 3-8 acres (often with a few rich peasants with larger farms and perhaps a nearby aristocrat with a massive estate), are nucleated into a village which is surrounded by farmland (as well as land not suitable or cleared for farming). If all of your household’s farmland was in one spot it was vulnerable to catastrophic failure, from pests, weather, warfare or what have you. So for farmers aiming not to maximize profits but to minimize risk (because in a bad year, you starve), the imperative is to spread out land holdings. In some cases this distribution might be handled by the leading figures of a village (the patriarchs of the most important families, generally), in order cases it was simply a product of who owned what. But the net impact was generally the same: rather than owning a single large plot of land, the peasant household owns (or otherwise has claim to) a lot of small parcels of land, often in small strips, spread over different ‘microclimates’ around the village. You can see an idealized image of just how fragmented the farm holdings were below:

Via Wikipedia, the plan for a ‘typical’ medieval manor. There’s a lot going on here (and this is a big farm with tenants, rather than a village with free-holding farmers, though note the village in the bottom center – that’s where the actual farm workers live), but what I want to focus on are the many small, narrow plots of land which would have been allotted to different families, so that each family had a little chunk of each ‘zone’ of the farmland.

Of course there were in these communities always larger landholders. These might be proper aristocrats with estates of hundreds of acres, often with entire villages contained within their landholdings. The gap between even a very poor aristocrat and your typical peasant was vast and unbridgeable. I am always put in mind here of the Bennets from Jane Austen’s Pride and Prejudice (1813), who are a relatively ‘poor’ family in the landed gentry (the sub-aristocracy, as it were) – nevertheless, Mr. Bennet’s estate (Longbourn) is large enough to include a village (also called Longbourn) from which he is in his rights to refuse Mr. Wickham entry. In short, even a relatively modest just-below-the-aristocracy-proper estate was large enough to include an entire village inside of it. We’ll not deal too much with these Big Men here – they get enough attention in any case – save as a source of employment for our peasants.

The other group to note, of course, are ‘rich peasants’ – landholders who are still peasants in the sense that they are engaged in the work of farming their land but who hold significantly more land than the labor available to a single family unit or household is going to be able to farm. These fellows show up very clearly in the Saint-Thibery data: in 1460 there were 27 households with between 30 and 60 setérées (18-36 acres) and 9 households with 100-250 setérées (60-150 acres). The latter group are our gentleman farmers, medieval proto-Bennets who function as employers for the smallest farmers who lack land, but the former group with those mid-sized holdings are our ‘rich peasants’ – not so wealthy to be entirely detached from the world of farming but still possessing substantially more resources than their neighbors. This is the sort of stratum in a Greek polis might have composed the bulk of the hoplite class or in the Roman Republic the ‘first class’ of infantry: not rich enough for a horse, but wealthy enough to afford expensive heavy armor. Naturally, these households are also going to wield disproportionate political power in the village.

A Peasant Community

Having all of that laid out, we can put it together to think through what a ‘model’ pre-modern peasant farming community looks like. Our peasants do not, for the most part, live in a town, but rather live in a village, which may in turn ‘orbit’ a larger settlement like a town. Villages range substantially in size, from very small settlements that might be only a dozen households to large villages of around 100 households (Saint-Thibery, discussed above, was a very large village of 189 households, in part because it had a substantial abbey in it (dating from the 8th century), which preserved the records used to discuss it). ‘Typical’ village size is trickier, but the mean seems to be around 30-60 households or so.20

As noted above, the mean size of our households is around 4-5, so our 30-60 household village has anywhere from 120 to 300 people in it. A disproportionate number of those individuals are going to live in larger households, around 6 or 7 people, as noted above, but equally there are going to be a handful of small households consisting of widows or widowers. Those houses aren’t going to be stretched out at random, but rather nucleated into a core settlement, with farmland radiating out from the village core. I should note, nearly everyone in a village of this size is going to be a peasant farmer – settlements this small aren’t going to have many, if any, specialist craftworkers or something like their own mill.21 A tavern or public house is somewhat more likely, but if there is, there will only be one. For specialist craftwork – metalwork, for instance – a peasant may have to go to another village or into town, or else rely on itinerant craftworkers (though as we’ll see, these households can produce most of what they need themselves).

Land holdings in the village are unlikely to be equal, though the precise breakdown of land holding patterns are going to vary a lot from one society to the next and in a lot of cases we simply cannot observe this clearly. I can’t speak to an ‘average’ or even ‘typical’ distribution, but something like what we see in Saint-Thibery might be broadly normal ‘rule of thirds,’ – about a third of the land controlled by large, potentially absentee landlords (aristocracy, gentry, church – the ‘big men‘) who we might understand as outside of the core ‘population’ of the village, another third controlled by a handful of wealthy peasant households who might represent about a fifth of the households and the remaining third owned by the meaning four-fifths of the peasant households.22 That is going to very naturally play into the hierarchy of relationships in the village, both the presence of the ‘big men’ – who are generally distant and ‘outside’ the village, often literally – but also the ‘rich peasants,’ who will be the leading voices of village politics by dint of their greater resources.

But most of the population of the village are not ‘rich peasants,’ but just regular peasants, whose landholdings are far more humble, on the order of 3-8 acres, with some households on even less than this. As we’ll see, many of those households are going to need to reach beyond their meager landholdings, something that the larger landholders – rich peasants and aristocrats alike – absolutely rely on.

Finally, we have the households themselves, with most of the people living in households of around 5-7 persons, most of whom will be kin, but many households will have a non-kin member or two (again, hired hands, enslaved laborers, very distant kin lodging, unrelated lodgers, etc.). Each household in turn functions largely as a single economic unit: one pantry or larder, one set of property, one house, rather than separate pools of resources. As we’ll see, households are not only hierarchical, but specialize labor based on gender and age (that is, men, women and children do different sorts of necessary work; everyone works).

So that is our baseline: a collection of a few dozen households of around 5-7 individuals each, most on very small plots of land to form our village. Next week we’ll look at how this reality is shaped by fertility and mortality patterns, which is to say birth and death.

[syndicated profile] smbc_comics_feed

Posted by Zach Weinersmith



Click here to go see the bonus panel!

Hovertext:
Surely there's a LITTLE degradation? Maybe on weekends or Halloween?


Today's News:
[syndicated profile] galwednesday_tumblr_feed

lionofchaeronea:

Title: Penelope Unraveling Her Work at Night
Artist: Dora Wheeler Keith (American, 1856-1940)
Date: 1886
Genre: mythological art
Medium: silk embroidered with silk thread
Dimensions: 114.3 cm (45 in) high x 172.7 cm (68 in) wide
Location: Metropolitan Museum of Art, New York City, NY, USA

Profile

potofsoup: (Default)
potofsoup

About

#me
#mine
AO3
Patreon
Storenvy
potofsoupyfeels at gmail

Most Popular Tags

Style Credit

Expand Cut Tags

No cut tags
Page generated Jul. 12th, 2025 01:03 pm
Powered by Dreamwidth Studios